Summary: 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism

Most finan­cial experts on TV or in the news­pa­pers tend to adhere to the same the­o­ry: free mar­ket eco­nom­ics. With all these indi­vid­u­als espous­ing the same view­point, you might be mis­led into believ­ing that there is only one eco­nom­ic route to follow.

How­ev­er, you’d be incor­rect – there is plen­ty flawed with free mar­ket eco­nom­ics. Far from being a flaw­less, sci­en­tif­ic approach, it encom­pass­es numer­ous inac­cu­rate notions about how the econ­o­my and soci­ety func­tion. And there are oth­er method­olo­gies to con­sid­er, even if they are most­ly over­looked by the media.

In this book overview, you will learn pre­cise­ly what is amiss with free mar­ket cap­i­tal­ism and what we can all do to explore supe­ri­or alter­na­tives. After absorb­ing the sub­se­quent argu­ments, your com­pre­hen­sion of eco­nom­ics will be for­ev­er transformed.

Summary: 23 Things They Don't Tell You About Capitalism

OVERVIEW PART 1

DESPITE WHAT FREE-MARKET ECONOMISTS ASSERT, THEIR FIELD IS NOT AN IMPARTIAL NATURAL SCIENCE.

You might rec­ol­lect the mas­sive finan­cial cri­sis that swept the globe in 2008. You might also remem­ber that in the ensu­ing months, econ­o­mists were – exclud­ing bankers – the most dis­trust­ed pro­fes­sion­als world­wide. Nev­er­the­less, this back­lash towards econ­o­mists was far from unjust – it was a per­fect­ly ratio­nal reac­tion to their over­bear­ing demeanor in pre­ced­ing years. Quite frankly, econ­o­mists had become exces­sive­ly conceited.

One indi­ca­tor of econ­o­mists’ over­con­fi­dence was their con­vic­tion that only they were capa­ble of ful­ly com­pre­hend­ing the intri­ca­cies of eco­nom­ic the­o­ry. This led them to dis­re­gard any cri­tique of their beliefs as over­ly simplistic.

How­ev­er, this was, and remains, unequiv­o­cal­ly untrue. Instead of being exces­sive­ly intri­cate for out­siders, 95 per­cent of eco­nom­ics is basic com­mon sense.

You can per­ceive it like this. When you dine at a restau­rant, you under­stand the clean­li­ness stan­dards you expect even though you lack a qual­i­fied epi­demi­ol­o­gist’s cre­den­tials. And it’s no dif­fer­ent for eco­nom­ics; the fun­da­men­tal prin­ci­ples of the dis­ci­pline can be grasped by any­one. After all, you don’t have to be the head of a cen­tral bank to real­ize that a nation should­n’t risk all its resources on pre­car­i­ous investments.

This arro­gance fur­ther led main­stream eco­nom­ic edu­ca­tion to dis­cred­it any dif­fer­ing theories.

Over the past few decades, a spe­cif­ic eco­nom­ic the­o­ry has held sway: neo-clas­si­cal free mar­ket the­o­ry. This ide­ol­o­gy pre­sup­pos­es that every indi­vid­ual in soci­ety acts as a log­i­cal, self-cen­tered agent, who only crafts an eco­nom­ic deci­sion by assess­ing how much it will prof­it them. The eco­nom­ic pro­fes­sion began to view this the­o­ry almost as a nat­ur­al sci­ence, lead­ing them to con­cen­trate exces­sive­ly on a nor­ma­tive the­o­ry rather than its appli­ca­tion in the real world.

But instead of being an impar­tial sci­ence like physics, eco­nom­ics is a social sci­ence. This implies there are numer­ous con­ceiv­able alter­na­tive the­o­ries – each just as sub­stan­ti­at­ed as the free mar­ket approach.

OVERVIEW PART 2

DESPITE WHAT FREE MARKET ECONOMISTS MAINTAIN, INDIVIDUALS CANNOT FORM ENTIRELY RATIONAL ECONOMIC DECISIONS.

Back in 1997, two econ­o­mists named Robert Mer­ton and Myron Scholes were hon­ored with the Nobel Prize in their domain. Their hypothe­ses pre­dom­i­nant­ly rest­ed on the notion that when mak­ing eco­nom­ic choic­es – such as where to invest their funds or which item to pur­chase – peo­ple made entire­ly ratio­nal decisions.

Post receiv­ing such a pres­ti­gious award, the two econ­o­mists put their the­o­ries into prac­tice. Nonethe­less, instead of amass­ing sig­nif­i­cant wealth, they found their com­pa­nies bank­rupt, not once but twice in lit­tle over a decade!

The fail­ure of Mer­ton and Scholes imparts one cru­cial les­son to us. You can­not antic­i­pate human beings to always behave rationally.

Why?

To make ratio­nal deci­sions, indi­vid­u­als must con­sid­er every con­ceiv­able detail. For instance, when deter­min­ing where to allo­cate our life sav­ings, we need to be aware of every prob­a­ble sce­nario, every alter­nate pos­si­bil­i­ty, and so forth. Only when armed with all this infor­ma­tion can we make the finest choice.

How­ev­er, in today’s world, it’s impos­si­ble to assim­i­late every iota of infor­ma­tion before mak­ing a deci­sion, hence our deci­sions can­not be whol­ly rational.

Nonethe­less, this does­n’t imply that we act com­plete­ly irra­tional­ly. Instead, we oper­ate under bound­ed ratio­nal­i­ty. We strive dili­gent­ly to be ratio­nal, we just lack the men­tal capac­i­ty to for­mu­late the per­fect deci­sion. But how can we adjust our eco­nom­ic cog­i­ta­tion to accom­mo­date this?

To aid us in mak­ing the most judi­cious deci­sions, the gov­ern­ment must inter­vene in the mar­ket to con­fine our eco­nom­ic options. If we are only pre­sent­ed choic­es whose ram­i­fi­ca­tions we can grasp, we can com­mence mak­ing bet­ter deci­sions. The gov­ern­ment already fol­lows this approach in oth­er domains. For instance, the author­i­ties pre­vent us from acquir­ing drugs with unknown side effects or auto­mo­biles with sub­stan­dard safe­ty mea­sures. Why should­n’t they extend the same reg­u­la­tions to the finan­cial sector?

OVERVIEW PART 3

HUMANS ARE NOT ENTIRELY SELFISH; WE OFTEN ACT BASED ON ALTRUISTIC CONCERNS.

Have you ever felt enticed to abscond with­out set­tling the fare for your cab ride? The like­li­hood is that, unless the dri­ver par­takes in sprint­ing like Usain Bolt, you could effort­less­ly flee. Nonethe­less, despite the notion occa­sion­al­ly cross­ing your mind, you always dis­card it and remit your fare.             

Yet, as rea­son­able as set­tling your cab fare may appear, free mar­ket econ­o­mists would con­tend that you are act­ing irra­tional­ly. They argue that we are all pre­dis­posed to act self­ish­ly and ergo we should per­pet­u­al­ly abscond with­out payment.

To elu­ci­date why we seem to defy their the­o­ry, free mar­ket econ­o­mists point to the hid­den advan­tages and penal­ties relat­ed to our actions. These are the costs and ben­e­fits that, though not imme­di­ate­ly dis­cernible, will hold sway in the long run.

Con­se­quent­ly, the ratio­nale for set­tling our cab fares is that we don’t wish to amass a rep­u­ta­tion as a fare evad­er. An indi­vid­ual brand­ed with such a rep­u­ta­tion would be utter­ly shunned by taxi dri­vers and would nev­er secure anoth­er cab ride.

How­ev­er, the the­o­ry of con­cealed costs and penal­ties floun­ders in a self-cen­tered society.

Let’s revis­it the cab illus­tra­tion. If we abscond­ed, the respon­si­bil­i­ty of penal­iz­ing us would devolve upon the taxi dri­ver. He would need to give chase, demand our fare, and prob­a­bly snap our pho­to­graph to exhib­it to oth­er taxi dri­vers in the vicin­i­ty. Through­out this endeav­or, his cab would remain entire­ly unat­tend­ed, sus­cep­ti­ble to theft or harm.

If he were to only look out for him­self, there would be no advan­tage for him — the fare he’d reclaim would be mea­ger and why should he aid oth­er taxi dri­vers by trackingus down?

The real­i­ty is that we com­pen­sate for our taxi jour­ney because we pri­or­i­tize val­ues such as integri­ty, integri­ty, and rev­er­ence, rather than sim­ply self-interest.

OVERVIEW PART 4

THE ECONOMY DOES NOT REMUNERATE INDIVIDUALS FAIRLY.

Do you con­cur with the asser­tion “we should all receive what we mer­it”? It seems ratio­nal, does­n’t it? Nev­er­the­less, if you orig­i­nate from a wealthy nation, you might need to reeval­u­ate this notion. If you were remu­ner­at­ed based on what the mar­ket deems fit­ting, you may observe a rapid decline in your earn­ings. How could this be?

This occurs because the salaries of labor­ers in devel­oped nations are shield­ed from mar­ket forces, keep­ing them ele­vat­ed regard­less of the job’s value.

For instance, irre­spec­tive of your pro­fes­sion­al occu­pa­tion, there are indi­vid­u­als in oth­er coun­tries will­ing to per­form it for a low­er wage. You are exempt from this com­pe­ti­tion due to gov­ern­men­tal pro­tec­tion of your job, main­tain­ing your income arti­fi­cial­ly high.

Addi­tion­al­ly, this elab­o­rates that your earn­ings are dic­tat­ed not by your skills, but sole­ly by the com­mu­ni­ty you reside in. Resid­ing in a pros­per­ous, indus­tri­ous com­mu­ni­ty will ele­vate your income due to oth­ers. Even the most indo­lent, least pro­duc­tive labor­er in such a soci­ety will earn more than a dili­gent work­er in an impov­er­ished nation.

This dis­par­i­ty in wages also pre­vails with­in indi­vid­ual societies.

Indi­vid­u­als posi­tioned at the high­er ech­e­lons of soci­ety will amass earn­ings far sur­pass­ing what they right­ly deserve com­pared to those at the bot­tom. For instance, in the ear­ly 1990s, top exec­u­tives wit­nessed a wage surge 100 times that of an aver­age work­er. Two decades lat­er, this mar­gin had sky­rock­et­ed to 400 times.

Is the exec­u­tive tru­ly worth 400 times more than the annu­al out­put of the work­er? The evi­dence sug­gests oth­er­wise; the typ­i­cal exec­u­tive is sim­ply not 400 times more effi­cient than the aver­age labor­er. Con­se­quent­ly, their increase is not jus­ti­fied in mar­ket terms.

SUMMARY PT 5: A ROBUST MANUFACTURING SECTOR IS MORE CRUCIAL FOR ECONOMIC EXPANSION THAN A VIBRANT SERVICE OR TECHNOLOGY ECONOMY.

How do you react when you pass by an aban­doned, dete­ri­o­rat­ing fac­to­ry? If you inhab­it the devel­oped world, you may asso­ciate it with nar­ra­tives of domes­tic indus­try decline. How­ev­er, such per­cep­tions are erroneous.

Peo­ple often mis­in­ter­pret sta­tis­tics, assum­ing that the reduc­tion in man­u­fac­tur­ing employ­ment sig­ni­fies dimin­ished indus­try, where­as it indi­cates enhanced efficiency.

Despite this, numer­ous pol­i­cy­mak­ers pro­pose that emerg­ing nations should con­tem­plate tran­si­tion­ing from man­u­fac­tur­ing to ser­vice and knowl­edge economies. Nev­er­the­less, this tran­si­tion could be detri­men­tal to the over­all economy.

For instance, ser­vice indus­tries, like retail or the IT sec­tor, have expand­ed over recent decades. Yet reliance on this sec­tor might pose risks.

One obsta­cle with the ser­vice indus­try is its slug­gish pro­duc­tiv­i­ty growth rates. Enhanc­ing pro­duc­tiv­i­ty in a ser­vice may lead to a com­pro­mised ser­vice qual­i­ty. For exam­ple, reduc­ing a Mac­beth pro­duc­tion to a mere ten min­utes may height­en pro­duc­tiv­i­ty, but sig­nif­i­cant­ly dimin­ish qual­i­ty. Con­se­quent­ly, an econ­o­my depen­dent on ser­vices may encounter rel­a­tive­ly slug­gish growth.              

Fur­ther­more, there is the knowl­edge econ­o­my, reliant on infor­ma­tion cre­ation and dis­sem­i­na­tion. Since the incep­tion of the inter­net, there have been claims of the knowl­edge econ­o­my’s vast potential.

Nonethe­less, this is exces­sive­ly exag­ger­at­ed. Con­trary to being a ground­break­ing inven­tion, the impact of the inter­net pales in com­par­i­son to pre­vi­ous com­mu­ni­ca­tion advance­ments. For instance, the tele­graph reduced mes­sage trans­mis­sion time from two weeks to 7.5 min­utes, a stag­ger­ing 2,500-fold speed increase.

In con­trast, the inter­net mere­ly improved effi­cien­cy from ten sec­onds (fax machine) to two sec­onds, a mere five­fold reduction.

OVERVIEW PART 6

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS RESULTED FROM THE DELIBERATE ACCUMULATION OF RISK IN THE SYSTEM.

The 2008 finan­cial cri­sis severe­ly impact­ed the glob­al econ­o­my, con­clud­ing over a decade of eco­nom­ic expan­sion and crip­pling major finan­cial institutions.

How­ev­er, numer­ous com­pa­nies pro­found­ly impact­ed by the crash, such as the insur­ance behe­moth AIG or invest­ment bank Lehman Broth­ers, played piv­otal roles in their demise.

Why?

Pre­ced­ing the cri­sis, the finan­cial sys­tem grew increas­ing­ly intri­cate. Finan­cial deriv­a­tives, like bonds, were engi­neered to diver­si­fy prod­ucts for trad­ing. Ini­tial­ly prof­itable, these deriv­a­tives con­cealed sub­stan­tial risk due to their complexity.

To devel­op these deriv­a­tives, pools of secu­ri­ties, such as mort­gage loans, were uti­lized to spawn var­i­ous finan­cial deriv­a­tives. With more deriv­a­tives fash­ioned from the same secu­ri­ty, risk spiraled.

Imag­ine con­struct­ing a tow­er­ing edi­fice on a mea­ger plot. As the struc­ture can­not expand hor­i­zon­tal­ly, you opt to ele­vate it with addi­tion­al storeys. What might unfold? With each new lev­el, sta­bil­i­ty wanes, and insta­bil­i­ty intensifies.

Com­pound­ing this, each new finan­cial prod­uct craft­ed was of infe­ri­or qual­i­ty. Anal­o­gous to our slen­der, bur­geon­ing house, each suc­ces­sive lev­el com­posed of sub­stan­dard mate­r­i­al like paper or plas­ticine. A struc­ture of such com­po­si­tion would inevitably collapse.

Albeit coun­tries world­wide endured from the crash, those most dev­as­tat­ed were those with dereg­u­lat­ed markets.

For exam­ple, Ire­land and Latvia, hav­ing lib­er­al­ized their mar­kets pre-cri­sis, endured severe reper­cus­sions; Ire­land’s econ­o­my con­tract­ed by 7.5%, while Latvi­a’s plum­met­ed by 16%.

OVERVIEW PART 7

DESPITE ECONOMISTS’ APPREHENSION OF GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC PLANNING, IT IS UNDERWAY AND PROVING EFFECTIVE.

Should the gov­ern­ment inter­vene in eco­nom­ic affairs?

Lib­er­al econ­o­mists rapid­ly refute this notion. They con­tend that state inter­ven­tion in the econ­o­my invari­ably leads to pan­de­mo­ni­um. They show­case con­trolled economies like those in the Sovi­et Bloc as prime exam­ples of the chaos entailed with state involve­ment. 

Con­trary to free mar­ket doc­trines, gov­ern­ments can and do play a piv­otal role in fos­ter­ing eco­nom­ic growth.

Gov­ern­ments often pos­sess supe­ri­or insight into the entire econ­o­my com­pared to indi­vid­ual com­pa­nies. This knowl­edge can be har­nessed to sup­port the most lucra­tive industries.

South Korea exem­pli­fies this. The elec­tron­ics giant LG orig­i­nal­ly aspired to con­cen­trate on tex­tiles, but gov­ern­men­tal fore­sight pro­pelled it into the elec­tron­ics domain, antic­i­pat­ing greater suc­cess in that sector.

This prin­ci­ple extends beyond devel­op­ing nations. The US gov­ern­ment metic­u­lous­ly nur­tured the ear­ly stages of the now-colossal

The inter­net, biotech­nol­o­gy, and avi­a­tion sectors.

How­ev­er, what made gov­ern­ment plan­ning effec­tive in these instances but not in Sovi­et Rus­sia? The crit­i­cal fac­tor is avoid­ing exces­sive control.

If the state attempts to man­age every aspect of the econ­o­my, like in the com­mu­nist world, it will encounter dif­fi­cul­ties. On the oth­er hand, if it offers guid­ance by set­ting broad objec­tives, such as tar­gets for infla­tion and reg­u­lat­ing inter­est rates, then it can achieve success.

In this capac­i­ty, the state func­tions some­what like a com­pa­ny’s chief exec­u­tive offi­cer. A CEO’s aim is to estab­lish strate­gic objec­tives to ensure their orga­ni­za­tion pro­gress­es steadi­ly in the right direc­tion. Sim­i­lar­ly, the state’s goal is to per­form the same func­tion for the entire economy.

OVERVIEW PART 8

SOCIAL WELFARE IS CRUCIAL FOR ROBUST ECONOMIC EXPANSION.

Through­out devel­oped nations, pro­po­nents of free-mar­ket eco­nom­ics are advo­cat­ing for reduc­tions in social wel­fare ben­e­fits by gov­ern­ments. They assert that pro­vid­ing ben­e­fits like unem­ploy­ment allowances or paid vaca­tions to indi­vid­u­als for not work­ing is counterproductive.

Despite the­o­ret­i­cal argu­ments, empir­i­cal evi­dence reveals that far from being a bur­den, social wel­fare is essen­tial for eco­nom­ic development.

This is evi­dent when exam­in­ing labor mar­kets. Nations offer­ing sig­nif­i­cant sup­port to the unem­ployed tend to have more vibrant economies than those with lim­it­ed assistance.

The ratio­nale behind this phe­nom­e­non is clear. In coun­tries with min­i­mal aid for the job­less, indi­vid­u­als fear los­ing their jobs, prompt­ing them to seek employ­ment in sec­tors deemed more secure. They often grav­i­tate toward sta­ble pro­fes­sions like health­care and law, which, while social­ly sig­nif­i­cant, do not fos­ter high lev­els of eco­nom­ic growth.

To fos­ter growth, it is nec­es­sary to encour­age peo­ple to ven­ture into riski­er, more entre­pre­neur­ial sec­tors of the econ­o­my. Pre­dictably, coun­tries pro­vid­ing sup­port for those who attempt but fail will con­sis­tent­ly out­per­form those where fail­ure results in poverty.

While evi­dence indi­cates that social wel­fare favors growth, the con­verse can be said of the free-mar­ket con­cept known as the trick­le-down effect.

Free-mar­ket sup­port­ers pro­pose that reduced gov­ern­ment spend­ing on wel­fare would obvi­ate the need for high tax­es. Sub­se­quent­ly, afflu­ent indi­vid­u­als could direct­ly invest their wealth in the econ­o­my. These invest­ments, pro­po­nents argue, would spur growth and job cre­ation as wealth trick­les down through the economy.

Nev­er­the­less, where this the­o­ry has been imple­ment­ed, it has not yield­ed the desired out­comes. In coun­tries that embraced free-mar­ket poli­cies in the 1980s, such as the Unit­ed States and Unit­ed King­dom, growth actu­al­ly decel­er­at­ed. As growth fal­tered, the trick­le-down effect stag­nat­ed, and cap­i­tal remained con­cen­trat­ed at the top.

For instance, between 1979 and 2006, the top one per­cent of earn­ers in the Unit­ed States more than dou­bled their share of nation­al income from ten per­cent to 22.9 percent.

OVERVIEW PART 9

WE MUST CEASE ATTEMPTS TO RECTIFY DEVELOPING NATIONS WITH INEFFECTIVE TOOLS.

A mul­ti­tude of politi­cians, econ­o­mists, and celebri­ties in the West firm­ly believe they pos­sess the solu­tions to erad­i­cate pover­ty in devel­op­ing countries.

Despite their con­fi­dence, a sub­stan­tial por­tion of the devel­oped world’s approach to impov­er­ished nations hinges on erro­neous beliefs.

One preva­lent fal­la­cy among West­ern pol­i­cy­mak­ers is attribut­ing pover­ty in devel­op­ing nations to struc­tur­al caus­es such as harsh cli­mates, land­locked geog­ra­phy, or rugged ter­rain. How­ev­er, if this were accu­rate, would coun­tries like Aus­tria and Switzer­land, with their land­locked and moun­tain­ous land­scapes, strug­gle economically?

Anoth­er mis­guid­ed West­ern notion is that devel­op­ing coun­tries lack the enter­pris­ing dri­ve seen in devel­oped nations. Yet the sta­tis­tics refute this claim: self-employed indi­vid­u­als account for 30–50% of the work­force in devel­op­ing nations, while in wealth­i­er West­ern coun­tries, only ten per­cent are self-employed. The asser­tion that non-West­ern coun­tries lack entre­pre­neur­ial fer­vor is unsubstantiated.

West­ern observers ques­tion­ing why devel­op­ing nations remain impov­er­ished should shift their focus clos­er to home. West­ern free-mar­ket poli­cies imposed on devel­op­ing nations large­ly con­tribute to their eco­nom­ic plight.

For instance, in the 1960s and 1970s, Sub-Saha­ran African nations expe­ri­enced steady growth due to pro­tec­tive mea­sures insti­tut­ed by their gov­ern­ments, which sub­si­dized and shield­ed domes­tic indus­tries from exter­nal com­pe­ti­tion. How­ev­er, when West­ern gov­ern­ments man­dat­ed mar­ket lib­er­al­iza­tion in the 1980s, the domes­tic economies faltered.

To reverse this trend and pro­pel devel­op­ing nations for­ward, it is imper­a­tive to recall the path­way through which West­ern nations achieved pros­per­i­ty. His­tor­i­cal pros­per­i­ty in the West stemmed from shield­ing their economies from for­eign com­pe­ti­tion in the nine­teenth cen­tu­ry. In the Unit­ed States, for­eign­ers were barred from act­ing as finan­cial direc­tors, and tar­iffs on import­ed goods reached 50 percent.

Would­n’t it be more pru­dent to allow devel­op­ing nations to fol­low this trajectory?

OVERVIEW PART 10

THE ISSUE LIES NOT WITH CAPITALISM ITSELF, BUT WITH ITS DESIGN.

Upon perus­ing this sum­ma­ry of the book, you may find your­self har­bor­ing frus­tra­tion towards cap­i­tal­ism. Before con­sid­er­ing Com­mu­nist Par­ty mem­ber­ship, rec­og­nize that it is not cap­i­tal­ism in its entire­ty at fault, but a spe­cif­ic vari­ant – free-mar­ket capitalism.

In real­i­ty, cap­i­tal­ism can serve as an effec­tive eco­nom­ic man­age­ment mechanism.

For instance, the prof­it motive, or the impe­tus to gen­er­ate prof­its, serves as a potent cat­a­lyst for inno­va­tion. Numer­ous inven­tions and advance­ments have arisen from indi­vid­u­als’ aspi­ra­tions to devel­op suc­cess­ful enterprises.

More­over, cap­i­tal­ism serves as an effi­cient coor­di­na­tor of the economy.

The mar­ket acts as a mech­a­nism that swift­ly allo­cates labor and cap­i­tal to areas of great­est need. With­out mar­ket guid­ance, soci­ety might end up with an over­sup­ply of musi­cians and a short­age of skilled tradespersons!

Nev­er­the­less, despite the ben­e­fits cap­i­tal­ism offers, it can har­bor sub­stan­tial risks with­out ade­quate regulation.

Con­sid­er cap­i­tal­ism akin to a car. A vehi­cle lack­ing safe­ty fea­tures like brakes or seat­belts is like­ly to even­tu­al­ly crash, result­ing in harm to occupants.

Regret­tably, the pre­vail­ing approach to cap­i­tal­ism advo­cates for a large­ly unreg­u­lat­ed sys­tem. How­ev­er, alter­na­tive strate­gies exist. Tran­si­tion­ing away from free mar­kets could allow for the estab­lish­ment of a supe­ri­or, fair­er, and safer cap­i­tal­ist structure.

One fea­si­ble approach involves inte­grat­ing the con­cept of bound­ed ratio­nal­i­ty – the notion that indi­vid­u­als make enhanced choic­es with a restrict­ed range of options.

By adopt­ing this method­ol­o­gy, empow­er­ing the gov­ern­ment with­in the eco­nom­ic sys­tem to cur­tail risky invest­ment choic­es by bankers could pro­mote informed and secure deci­sion-mak­ing with­in society.

The Core Lesson From this Book

Dis­re­gard the asser­tions of pro­fes­sion­al econ­o­mists that the free mar­ket is the sole method for eco­nom­ic reg­u­la­tion; there exist alter­na­tive, fair­er options that we can select from. We must con­cen­trate on these alter­na­tives to con­struct a supe­ri­or, more equi­table, and sta­ble world.

Action­able recommendation:

Exer­cise cau­tion when select­ing your polit­i­cal representatives.

Politi­cians often entice vot­ers by promis­ing tax reduc­tions. While appeal­ing ini­tial­ly, con­sid­er the reper­cus­sions of such cuts on pub­lic ser­vices. If you val­ue pub­lic ameni­ties, choos­ing an alter­na­tive can­di­date might be more beneficial.

Rate article
( No ratings yet )
Add a comment

18 + 19 =